Homo Homini Lupus: Is that the right way to approach Economic Security?
The discipline of International Relations, particularly
in the Realist tradition, seems to be woven around the notion of Homo Homini
Lupus. (Hu)Man is Wolf to (Hu) Man. But is this notion correct? Or is it just a
problem of perception? Realists tell us that it is either human nature or the structure
of the international system that makes conflict a recurring theme in our epic.
But the constructivists would like us to believe that reality is what we
perceive it to be (“Anarchy is what we make of it”). This debate has been
around for a long time. An even more interesting sector of this debate is
economic security.
So, what is economic security? – Economic
security can be defined as the ability of a nation to secure its economy from
external or internal threats. External threats include sanctions, wars,
embargos, blockades etc. Internal threats can constitute populism, physical
threats to the movement of goods, services and people within the country etc. It can also be said to be the ability of a
state, a bloc or even an international organization (IO) to provide prosperity and
relative economic equality to its members or citizens.
An essential question to ask here is this:
If security must be provided by the state, then it must be threatened by
another force. So, does this external or internal force exist in reality or is it
a result of mere perception? – This question is nothing but another way of
articulating the realist vs constructivist debate elucidated in the first
paragraph.
Countries pay great attention to their
trade balance, debt to GDP ratio, ease of doing business rankings and other key
indicators because it is thought that these indicators reflect not just the state
of the economy but also the ability of the government to secure livelihoods.
The second point is important when we think
of security studies and the basis on which the notion of economic security is constituted.
As the provider of livelihoods,
the logical next step for the state is to remove impediments on its ability to
do so. Thus, begins the process of securitization.
This process, does indeed have a strong
Realist scent to it. In addition to that, it is also difficult to fit this
process into a certain box. For instance, Robert Cox attempted to make an important
distinction when it comes to IR theories. He said that there were two kinds of
theories: problem-solving and critical theories. The problem-solving theories,
he said, were interested in identifying small issues within the existing system
and attempting to solve them while ignoring structural problems. On the other
hand, critical theories question the foundational assumptions of the existing
system.[i] Our topic of discussion somewhat transcends
this division as the Realist process of securitizing the economy neither solves
a problem nor does it attempt to question anything. All that it does is that it
makes the economy a protected object and identifies key threats to the
protected object. One cannot put this process into a clean-cut analytical box.
An
interesting example to examine this paradigm is the example of trade wars and particularly
the recent one going on between the US and China. The Trump Administration’s reason
for imposing tariffs on Chinese goods was ‘national security.’ The
Administration felt that large trade deficits with China constituted a threat
to national security[ii]
because this constituted an outflow of money and jobs from the United States. Money
(being key to the US’s commercial interests) and jobs (for economic and
political interests) are important elements of economic security.
The Trump administration is solving a problem,
as well as looking critically at a certain structural issue (the global trade structure
over here). This puts securitization beyond Cox’s analytical framework.
However, it does not answer the moot question: is the threat something that is
perceived or something that is real? To answer that, we must distinguish
between security issues and normal political issues[iii].
The securitized realm is where urgent action is necessary because the problem has
created a state of emergency. The normal political realm, on the other, is where
the issue has been ‘de-intensified.’ This distinction creates an element of
human agency in the conversation. It partly bends towards the constructionist angle,
because it shows that a certain issue can indeed be ‘de-intensified.’ But it still
does not attempt to question the role of the state. If the state continues to
be the protector, then is it the case that its assumptions about what
constitutes a security threat and what doesn’t will continue to drive our
outlook?
In that case, does China become a threat to
America’s economic security because the Trump Administration chose to interpret
economic data in a certain way? Perhaps. Is that a good thing?... The answer to
that is difficult. As Waever says in his assertions, playing a game with the powerful
also puts us in a situation where we are subjected to randomly changing
environments and rules[iv].
It is they who create the threat perception. Yet, accepting the reality that
governments are the actors who often have the authority to classify something
or someone as a security threat does not mean that the governments are
inherently wrong. Often, the perception of the state of economic security depends
on which party is in power and who has voted for them. The rightness of actions
depends on whom we ask.
To conclude, Homo Homini Lupus is not just
an exotic Latin saying. But it is also the basis on which securitization takes
place. A state can only securitize itself if it accepts that another entity is
intent and capable of damaging its interests. Whether that is right or not is
relative. That is the beauty of the relativity of security studies.
References:
Huang, Yukon. “The U.S.-China Trade War Has Become a Cold War.” Carnegie Endowment for International Peace. Accessed February 4, 2022. https://carnegieendowment.org/2021/09/16/u.s.-china-trade-war-has-become-cold-war-pub-85352.
Krause, Keith, and
Michael Williams. “Security and ‘Security Studies.’” The Oxford Handbook of
International Security, 2018, 13–28.
https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780198777854.013.2.
Schouten, Peer. “Theory Talk #37: Robert Cox.” Theory
Talk #37: Robert Cox. Accessed February 4, 2022.
http://www.theory-talks.org/2010/03/theory-talk-37.html.
Waever, Ole. “
Securitization and Desecuritization.” On Security, n.d.
[i]
Schouten, Peer. “Theory Talk #37: Robert Cox.” Theory Talk #37: Robert Cox.
Accessed February 4, 2022.
http://www.theory-talks.org/2010/03/theory-talk-37.html.
[ii]
Huang, Yukon. “The U.S.-China Trade War Has Become a Cold War.” Carnegie
Endowment for International Peace. Accessed February 4, 2022.
https://carnegieendowment.org/2021/09/16/u.s.-china-trade-war-has-become-cold-war-pub-85352.
[iii]Krause,
Keith, and Michael Williams. “Security and ‘Security Studies.’” The Oxford
Handbook of International Security, 2018, 13–28.
https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780198777854.013.2.
[iv]
Waever, Ole. “ Securitization and Desecuritization.” On Security, n.d.
Comments
Post a Comment